Sunday, May 8, 2011

could china use its trade surplus ???

China is in the historically unusual position of being an immature
creditor: its own currency, the renminbi, is hardly used at
all in financing its huge trade (saving) surplus. Instead, the
world—particularly the Asian part of it—is still on a dollar
standard. The dollar is the invoice currency of choice for most
Chinese exports and imports and for open-market, that is,
nongovernment, controlled financial flows. So we have the
anomaly that the world’s largest creditor country cannot use
its own currency to finance foreign investments.
The lag in the international use of the renminbi is partly
because China’s domestic financial markets are not fully
developed. Interest rate restrictions as well as residual capital
controls on foreign exchange flows remain. But a more
fundamental constraint is that the U.S. dollar has the firstmover
advantage of being ensconced as “international
money.” World financial markets shun the use of more than
one or two national currencies for clearing international payments—
with the euro now in second place. But the euro’s
use in payments clearing is still pretty well confined to
Europe’s own backyard (Eastern Europe and former
European colonies). Thus, dollar dominance makes the internationalization
of the renminbi very difficult—although the
People’s Bank of China is trying hard to encourage the renminbi’s
use in international transacting on China’s immediate
borders.
The upshot is that China’s own currency is still not used
much in lending to foreigners. Foreigners won’t borrow from
Chinese banks in renminbi or issue renminbi- denominated
bonds in Shanghai. But, apart from direct investments abroad
by Chinese corporations, private finance for China’s trade
surplus would have to take the form of Chinese banks, insurance
companies, pension funds, and so on, acquiring liquid
foreign exchange assets—largely in dollars. But their domes
tic liabilities—bank deposits, annuity or pension liabilities—
are all denominated in renminbi. Because of this currency
mismatch, the exchange rate risks for China’s private
banks and other financial institutions are simply too great
for them to be international financial intermediaries, that is,
to lend to foreigners on a large scale.
China’s current large trade (saving) surpluses, which
run at about $200 billion to $300 billion per year, would
quickly cumulate to become much greater than the combined
net worth of all of China’s private financial institutions.
Because these private (nonstate) institutions would
refuse to accept the exchange risk (possible dollar depreciation)
of holding dollar assets on a significant scale, the
international intermediation of China’s saving surplus is
left to the central government. The problem is worsened by
American “China bashing” to appreciate the renminbi, the
expectation of which makes foreigners even
more loathe to borrow in renminbi—while stimulating
perverse inflows of hot money to China.
The upshot is that China’s central government
steps in to intermediate and control the
country’s saving surplus in several different
ways.
First, huge liquid official reserves of foreign
exchange, currently about $2.5 trillion, are
accumulated in the State Administration of
Foreign Exchange. Next, sovereign wealth funds
are created, like the China Investment
Corporation, which invests overseas in bonds,
equities, or real estate. Third, China’s large stateowned
enterprises such as SINOPEC are
encouraged to invest in, or partner with, foreign
oil companies in exploration and production.
And finally, quasi-barter aid programs in developing
countries generate a return flow of industrial
materials.
Regarding this last, China does not give
“aid” to African or Latin American countries in
the conventional form of liquid dollar deposits.
Instead, China’s overseas investments are combined
with aid under the fairly strict government
control of China’s Export-Import Bank or
the Department of Commerce. In return for
using state-owned construction companies to
build large-scale infrastructure for ports, railways,
power plants, and so on, the recipient
country agrees to repay China by giving it a
claim on a future stream of copper or iron ore or
oil or whatever mineral that the infrastructure
investments make possible, whence the “quasibarter”
nature of the deal. Because these foreign
aid/investment projects are under the
control of state-owned financial intermediaries, they
become effectively illiquid. They will not be suddenly
sold off and become part of hot money flows back into
China.